NEP: New Economics PapersBusiness, Economic and Financial History
Edited by: Bernardo Batiz-Lazo, Bristol Business School
Issue date: 2006-06-24
Papers: 7
Contents.
How occupied France financed its own exploitation in World War II.
Date: 2006-03
By: Filippo Occhino (Department of Economics, Rutgers University, New Brunswick.) Kim Oosterlinck (Centre Emile Bernheim, Solvay Business School, Université Libre de Bruxelles, Brussels.) Eugène N. White (Department of Economics, Rutgers University, New Brunswick.)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:sol:wpaper:06-012&r=his
The occupation payments made by France to Nazi Germany between 1940 and 1944 represent one of the largest recorded international transfers and contributed significantly to financing the overall German war effort. Using a neoclassical growth model that incorporates essential features of the occupied economy and the postwar stabilization, we assess the welfare costs of French policies that funded payments to Germany. Occupation payments required a 16 percent reduction of consumption for twenty years, with the draft of labor to Germany and wage and price controls adding substantially to this burden. Vichy?s postwar debt overhang would have demanded large budget surpluses; but inflation, which erupted after Liberation, reduced the debt well below its steady state level and redistributed the adjustment costs. The Marshall Plan played only a minor direct role, and international credits helped to substantially lower the nation?s burden.
Keywords: World War Two, France, Macroeconomy, Economic History, Exploitation.
JEL: E1 E6 N1 N4
Globalization, De-Industrialization and Mexican Exceptionalism 1750-1879
Date: 2006-06
By: Rafael Dobado GonzálezAurora Gómez GalvarriatoJeffrey G. Williamson
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:12316&r=his
Like the rest of the poor periphery, Mexico had to deal with de-industrialization forces between 1750 and 1913, those critical 150 years when the economic gap between the industrial core and the primary-product-producing periphery widened to such huge dimensions. Yet, from independence to mid-century Mexico did better on this score than did most countries around the periphery. This paper explores the sources of Mexican exceptionalism with de-industrialization. It decomposes those sources into those attributable to productivity events in the core and to globalization forces connecting core to periphery, and to those attributable to domestic forces specific to Mexico. It uses a neo-Ricardian model (with non-tradable foodstuffs) to implement the decomposition, and advocates a price dual approach, and develops a new price and wage data base 1750-1878. There were three forces at work that account for Mexican exceptional ism: first, the terms of trade and Dutch disease effects were much weaker; second, Mexico maintained secular wage competitiveness with the core; and third, Mexico had the autonomy to devise effective ways to foster industry. The first appears to have been the most important.
JEL: F1 N7 O2
Proposal for a Common Currency among Rich Democracies (Paper 1); One World Money, Then and Now (Paper 2)
Date: 2006-09-06
By: Richard N. Cooper (Paper 1) (Harvard University) Michael Bordo (Paper 2) (Economics Department, Rutgers University and Harvard University) Harold James (Paper 2) (History Department and Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:onb:oenbwp:127&r=his
Paper 1: This paper suggests that some time in the not-too-distant future the governments of the industrialized democracies ? concretely, the United States, the European Union, and Japan ? should consider establishing a common currency for their collective use. A common currency would credibly eliminate exchange rate uncertainty and exchange rate movements among major currencies, both of which are significant sources of disturbance to important economies. One currency would of course entail one monetary policy for the currency area, and a political mechanism to assure accountability. This proposal is not realistic today, but is set as a vision for the second or third decade into the 21st century. Europeans, in creating EMU, have taken a major step in the direction indicated. Their idea could be taken further. Paper 2: In this paper, we look at the major arguments for monetary simplification and unification befo re explaining why the nineteenth century utopia is an idea whose time has gone, not come.
The Boskin Commission Report: A Retrospective One Decade Later
Date: 2006-06
By: Robert J. Gordon
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:12311&r=his
This paper provides a retrospective on the 1996 Boskin Commission Report, Toward a More Accurate Measure of the Cost of Living, and its famous estimate that the CPI in 1995-96 was upward biased by 1.1 percent per year. The paper summarizes the report’s methods, findings, and recommendations, and then reviews the criticisms that appeared soon after the Report was issued. Post-Boskin changes in the CPI are summarized and assessed, as is recent research on related issues. The paper sharply distinguishes two questions. First, with what we know now, what should the Commission have concluded about CPI bias in 1995-96? Second, what is the bias now after the many improvements introduced into the CPI since the Commission’s Report? About the first question, my own recent research on apparel and rental housing indicates a substantial downward bias in the CPI over much of the twentieth century, diminishing in size after 1985. Incorporating these findings into the Boskin matrix would reduce its 0.6 percent annual upward bias due to quality change and new products to a smaller 0.4 percent bias. However, this is more than offset by the stunning discrepancy over 2000-06 in the chain-weighted C-CPI-U compared to the traditional CPI-U, indicating that the Commission greatly understated the magnitude of upper-level substitution bias. This retrospective evaluation suggests that the Boskin bias estimate for 1995-96 should have been 1.2 to 1.3 percent, not 1.1 percent. Current upward bias in the CPI is estimated to have declined from the revised 1.2-1.3 percent in the Boskin era to about 0.8 percent today. Yet the Boskin report, like most contemporary studies of quality change, failed to place sufficient value on the value of new products and on increased longevity. Allowing for these, today’s bias is at least 1.0 percent per year or perhaps even higher.
JEL: I1 I11
Do Institutions Matter? – An Analysis of the Russian Competition Policy in the Period of Transformation
Date: 2006-06
By: Marina Grusevaja
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pot:vwldis:88&r=his
The internationalisation of the French aerospace industry in the 1990s: a break with the past? (In French)
Date: 2006
By: Christophe Carrincazeaux and Vincent Frigant
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:grs:wpegrs:2006-15&r=his
The 1990s are often described as the decade when the aerospace industry broke with the past. The drop in military orders that occurred early in the decade, the adoption in both the defence and civil markets of more competitive modes of regulation, the arrival at maturity of several big civil programmes and a host of privatisations – all had a durable impact on the aerospace industry in France. A general consensus exists about these changes, but few empirical studies have actually tried to measure the extent of their impact on the sector. To make up for this, we have carried out a statistical study of the structural transformations befalling the aerospace industry through the analysis of one specific problem: firms? internationalisation. We have used four databases, including for the first time the EEIG survey of intra-firm trade, to assess whether French firms did in fact deeply modify their internationalisation behaviour over the period 1993-1999. We come to mixed conclusions, the suggestion being that what the sector experienced was more of an evolution than a major upheaval. Although certain components of firms? internationalisation trajectories were clearly altered (like the French State?s presence in the sector or sales internationalisation), others evolved much more slowly (like foreign companies? penetration in France and French companies? productive internationalisation). Summarily, we can say that productive internationalisation remained modest in comparison with sales internationalisation.
Keywords: Globalization, Aerospace industry, Privatization, Multinational Firms
JEL: F2 F23 L62
«True and Fair view» ou le concept de l’image fidèle.
Date: 2006-06
By: Jacqueline Haverals (Centre Emile Bernheim, Solvay Business School, Université Libre de Bruxelles, Brussels.)
URL: http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:sol:wpaper:06-011&r=his
Conformément à la quatrième Directive et à sa transposition en droit interne belge, l?objectif principal de la comptabilité est d?établir des comptes annuels qui reflètent une image fidèle de la situation financière et patrimoniale d?une entreprise. Cette contribution poursuit un double objectif, à savoir retracer l?historique du concept de l?image fidèle, traduction officielle de l?expression » true and fair view » empruntée aux comptables anglais et définir ses principaux attributs et caractéristiques dans les acceptions européennes et anglo-saxonnes. Elle s?articule autour des quatre sections suivantes : La première section retrace l?origine de l?image fidèle dans le droit comptable européen et le droit comptable belge. La deuxième section tente d?éclaircir la signification de cette notion qui, bien que reprise internationalement, n?a jamais été définie. La troisième section identifie et caractérise l?image fidèle au sein des courants comptables européen continental et anglo-saxon. La quatrième section conclut l?étude.
Keywords: true and fair view, accounting, tax law.
JEL: M41 H20
Olá!
Para se inscrever nos cursos Instituto FEP o interessado deve comparecer no endereço abaixo no dia e horário indicado a seguir: INSCRIÇÕES: aos sábados dias 03/01 e 10/01 10h00 ás 16h00. Rua Arnaldo Vallardi Portilho, 10, Penha (próximo ao metrô penha)– S. Paulo Observação importante: Levar o xérox do RG e CPF e comprovante residência o valor da matricula é de R$ 50,00.
Implantação de Redes.Das 14h00 ás 16h30 aos sábados 50vagas, Ter no mínimo 13 anos e já ter cursado a sexta série.
Montagem e Manutenção de Micro das 9:00 as 11:30 aos sábados 100 vagas Ter no mínimo 13 anos e já ter cursado a sexta série.
Inglês técnico: das 12h00 as 13h30
Inglês técnico: das 17h00 as 18h30
Inglês Básico I e II e intermediário, Espanhol Básico I e II e intermediário das 9:00 as 13:30 e das 14:00as 18:30 aos sábados aos sábados 200 vagas, Ter no mínimo 13 anos e já ter cursado a sexta série.
Preparatório para Concurso Público disciplina Português, Matemática, Direito, informática, das 90:00 as 17:30 aos sábados 120 vagas, aparte de 17 anos.
O Maximo de aluno por sala de aula é de 30.
Local onde você pode escolher para estudar: zona norte, zona leste.As inscrições só poderão ser feitas, no endereço citado.
Professores graduados e professores da USP.
Carteirinha para obter desconto, em vários estabelecimentos inclusivo faculdades, cinemas etc.
Taxa de manutenção mensal é de R$25,00 (exceto preparatório para Concurso público $50,00).
A duração dos cursos é de 6 meses,podendo da continuidade aos cursos Inglês-Espanhol ,
Certificado de conclusão.
Rakel1867@itelefonica.Com.br Informação 2023-2060 ou 7247-1763.
INSTITUTO FEP inscreve para cursos de Qualidade preços acessíveis:
Com o objetivo de oferecer oportunidade àqueles que queiram fazer um curso de qualidade e baixo custo, o instituto, em seu núcleo próximo ao metrô penha oferece quatro.Com professores graduados e professores da USP.
Curso acessível ·Taxa de inscrição de R$50,00.
Taxa de manutenção mensal de R$30, 00, Exceto preparatório R$50,00 mensal.
Os interessados podem optar por um dos seguintes cursos Semestrais:
Com vagas limitadas;
Implantação de Redes. Ter no mínimo 13 anos e já ter cursado a sexta série.
Montagem e Manutenção de Micro Ter no mínimo 13 anos e já ter cursado a sexta série.
Inglês-Espanhol Básico Ter no mínimo 13 anos e já ter cursando a sexta série.
Preparatório para Concurso Público disciplina Português, Matemática, Direito, informática, aparte de 17 anos.
Inglês Técnico para computação, Ter no mínimo 13 anos e já ter cursado a sexta série.
Carteirinha para obter desconto em Faculdade em outros estabelecimentos.
Taxa de Matricula R$50,00
Taxa de manutenção mensal é de R$30,00 (exceto preparatório para Concurso público $50,00).
Certificado de conclusão, o aluno não pode ter mais de 3 faltas sem justificativa por escrito.
Os professores graduados e professores da USP
Zona Norte cel:8913-3031 Zona leste Rua Arnaldo Vallardi Portilho, 10, Penha (próximo ao metrô penha)– S. Paulo – informação 2687-0925. A matricula devem ser feitas: aos sábado último Dias 18/04 e 25/04 somente esses dias, das 10h00 ás 16h00.Leva Valor da matricula é de R$50, 00 xerox do RG E CPF comprovante residência..